Results for “prediction market”
326 found

ngdp minimalism

Could we circulate this as a petition and have the whole world sign it, paw prints and all?:

Ken Duda sent me some ideas that form a useful second step, still falling well short of NGDP targeting (an idea rapidly gaining popularity among the elite.)  Here’s Ken’s still extremely modest second set of steps:

1) publishing an NGDP forecast

2) publishing a forecast of how policy instrument settings would affect NGDP (“if we were to raise interest rates, we’d expect the NGDP level to be X% lower than if we hold interest rates at zero”).

3) forecasting what are desirable levels of NGDP, i.e., what NGDP level-path would be most consistent with the dual mandate, or what NGDP level-path would be consistent with what level of unemployment or inflation

4) operating a prediction market for any of the three above

I can’t even imagine how anyone could oppose any of those 4 steps, even if they were 100% opposed to NGDP targeting.  How would that information not be useful?

That is from Scott Sumner, the full post is here.

I, Rose

Valentine’s Day is this week and what better way to celebrate than to appreciate the economics of roses!

A rose isn’t just a symbol of love it’s a symbol of global cooperation coordinated by the invisible hand. In The Price System, the just released section of our principles of microeconomics course, we feature two rose videos (along with videos on the great economic problem, speculation, prediction markets and more). Here’s the first; I, Rose. Tomorrow, A Price is a Signal Wrapped up in an Incentive. Enjoy.

*Trillion Dollar Economists*

That is the new book by Robert E. Litan and it is the single best attempt to answer the question of what good economists have done the world (I am also a big fan of Alex’s earlier edited volume, Entrepreneurial Economics on this topic, the Litan is more current).  The subtitle is How Economists and their Ideas have Transformed Business.

Every chapter is clear and convincing, and the topics include optimization, regression, Moneyball, experimental economics, auctions, consulting, matchmaking (romantic and otherwise), finance, deregulation, the telecommunications revolution, Hal Varian at Google, prediction markets, and much more.

Definitely recommended.

Should the Future Get a Vote?

Philosopher Thomas Wells argues that future citizens need the vote today:

…future generations must accept whatever we choose to bequeath them, and they have no way of informing us of their values. In this, they are even more helpless than foreigners, on whom our political decisions about pollution, trade, war and so on are similarly imposed without consent. Disenfranchised as they are, such foreigners can at least petition their own governments to tell ours off, or engage with us directly by writing articles in our newspapers about the justice of their cause. The citizens of the future lack even this recourse.

The asymmetry between past and future is more than unfair. Our ancestors are beyond harm; they cannot know if we disappoint them. Yet the political decisions we make today will do more than just determine the burdens of citizenship for our grandchildren. They also concern existential dangers such as the likelihood of pandemics and environmental collapse. Without a presence in our political system, the plight of future citizens who might suffer or gain from our present political decisions cannot be properly weighed. We need to give them a voice.

But how can we solve this problem? Wells has some very good insights:

If current citizens can’t help but be short-sighted, perhaps we should consider introducing agents who can vote in a far-seeing and impartial way. They would need to be credibly motivated to defend the basic interests of future generations as a whole, rather than certain favoured subsets, and they would require the expertise to calculate the long-term actuarial implications of government policies.

But then his solution turns laughable:

Such voters would have to be more than human. I am thinking of civic organisations, such as charitable foundations, environmentalist advocacy groups or non-partisan think tanks.

Well’s solution (give these groups votes) is so tied to his conception of what the “enlightened” future will bring that it clearly fails the far-seeing, impartiality, credibly motivated and expertise requirements that he outlines as desirable. We need not conclude, however, that Well’s plea is disingenuous or impossible but we do need a better implementation.

Robin Hanson’s government of prediction markets (“futarchy“) is a better approach. It is know well understood that relative to other institutions prediction markets draw on expertise to produce predictions that are far seeing and impartial. What is less well understood is that through a suitable choice of what is to be traded, prediction markets can be designed to be credibly motivated by a variety of goals including the interests of future generations.

To understand futarchy note that a prediction market in future GDP would be a good predictor of future GDP. Thus, if all we cared about was future GDP, a good rule would be to pass a policy if prediction markets estimate that future GDP will be higher with the policy than without the policy. Of course, we care about more than future GDP; perhaps we also care about environmental quality, risk, inequality, liberty and so forth. What Hanson’s futarchy proposes is to incorporate all these ideas into a weighted measure of welfare. Prediction markets would then be used to predict and make policy choices based on future welfare. Incorporated within the measure of welfare could be factors like environmental quality many years into the future. 

Note, however, that even this assumes that we know what people in the future will care about. Here then is the final meta-twist. We can also incorporate into our measure of welfare predictions of how future generations will define welfare. We could, for example, choose a rule such that we will pass policies that increase future environmental quality unless a prediction market in future definitions of welfare suggests that future generations will change their welfare standards. It sounds complicated but then so is the problem.

In short, more than any other form of government, futarchy is based on far seeing, impartial, expertise driven and credibly motivated predictions of future welfare and it is flexible enough to allow for a wide definition of welfare including taking into account the interests of future generations.

Hat tip: Carl Close.

Should we regulate Bitcoin?

There is a new paper by Jerry Brito, Houman Shadab, and Andrea Castillo, the abstract is here:

The next major wave of Bitcoin regulation will likely be aimed at financial instruments, including securities and derivatives, as well as prediction markets and even gambling. While there are many easily regulated intermediaries when it comes to traditional securities and derivatives, emerging bitcoin-denominated instruments rely much less on traditional intermediaries. Additionally, the block chain technology that Bitcoin introduced for the first time makes completely decentralized markets and exchanges possible, thus eliminating the need for intermediaries in complex financial transactions.

In this article we survey the type of financial instruments and transactions that will most likely be of interest to regulators, including traditional securities and derivatives, new bitcoin-denominated instruments, and completely decentralized markets and exchanges. We find that bitcoin derivatives would likely not be subject to the full scope of regulation under the Commodities and Exchange Act because such derivatives would likely involve physical delivery (as opposed to cash settlement) and would not be capable of being centrally cleared. We also find that some laws, including those aimed at online gambling, do not contemplate a payment method like Bitcoin, thus placing many transactions in a legal gray area.

Following the approach to Bitcoin taken by FinCEN, we conclude that other financial regulators should consider exempting or excluding certain financial transactions denominated in Bitcoin from the full scope of the regulations, much like private securities offerings and forward contracts are treated. We also suggest that to the extent that regulation and enforcement becomes more costly than its benefits, policymakers should consider and pursue strategies consistent with that new reality, such as efforts to encourage resilience and adaptation.

Along related lines, you might consider Adam Thierer’s excellent new book Permissionless Innovation: The Continuing Case for Comprehensive Technological Freedom.

Lots of assorted links today

1. Meet the two artists living in a giant hamster wheel.  And decentralized Bitcoin prediction markets.

2. Do women respond more to grades than do men?  And Ph.d. candidates as fashion models.  And new and fairly comprehensive study of the economics of the sex trade.

3. Useful origami microscope for less than a dollar.

4. Winkbooks, a new book review site, I believe from Boing Boing and Wired.

5. With proper adjustments, cohabitation before marriage does not predict divorce.

6. Full transcript and video of the Edward Snowden talk.  And has Snowden improved our cyberdefense credibility?

7. The world’s longest high-speed rail line has just opened in China.

8. Company reverses drug decision.

Robert Shiller Nobelist

Robert Shiller is best known for warning about the internet stock market bubble and later the housing bubble. What is most impressive to me, however, is that most people who think that markets can be inefficient are anti-market. Shiller’s solution to market problems, however, is more markets! The housing market, for example, has traditionally had two problems. Since each house is unique there has been no market index of housing prices so that people couldn’t easily see bubbles and if they could see them on the ground there was no easy way to short the market (to try to profit from the bubble in a way that would moderate the bubble). Moreover, because there haven’t been good housing indexes a very large amount of each average person’s wealth has been tied up with an asset that can fluctuate substantially in price. Most house buyers, in other words, are putting all their eggs in one basket and crossing their fingers that the basket doesn’t go bust. In recent years, that has been a very unfortunate bet.

Shiller’s solution to the problems in the housing market has been to make the market better—he created with Case and Weiss–the Case-Shiller Index. For the first time, it’s possible to see in real time housing prices and compare with averages over time and it possible to buy options and futures on the index which will help for forecasting. Moreover, it’s possible that in the future insurance products can be built based on local versions of the index–thus you could insure yourself against big declines in the price of housing in your neighborhood.

Shiller’s housing index is also a window into how macro markets could also be used to create livelihood insurance, a type of private unemployment insurance. Moral hazard and adverse selection make it difficult to protect any single individual from unemployment but indexes in the unemployment rate of dentists or construction workers could be used to provide some insurance for workers in these fields when conditions in their entire industry are poor.

I featured one of Shiller’s biggest ideas in Entrepreneurial Economics, markets in GDP. A GDP market would allow shares of GDP to be bought and sold, add to this Hansonian prediction markets and you are long way towards an ideal way to evaluate the effect of major policies. Moreover, a GDP market would allow the creation of many insurance products. We are all less diversified than is ideal. It would be optimal to trade some shares in US GDP for shares in World GDP which is more stable. We can do this if we create Shiller GDP markets throughout the world.

Shiller’s book Macro Markets is truly visionary and I hope the Nobel brings a lot of attention to these ideas.

Robert Shiller, Nobel Laureate

Robert Shiller spent much of his career at Yale University.  He is a famous economist for his analysis of speculative bubbles and price overreaction to new information, first in stock markets and then later in real estate markets.  He has been a leading candidate for a Nobel Prize for some time now.

Here is Shiller’s home page.  Here is Shiller on Wikipedia.  Here are short columns by Shiller on Project Syndicate.  He also writes regularly for the Sunday New York Times, and some of his columns are here.  Here is a 2005 David Leonhardt profile of Shiller.

Shiller’s most famous piece is from 1981, “Do Stock Prices Move Too Much to be Justified by Subsequent Changes in Dividends?”  Here Shiller developed the very important “variance bounds test” for scrutinizing the rationality of stock prices.  The intuition runs like this.  Let’s say you were trying to forecast the result of Miami Heat vs. San Antonio Spurs.  The results of the actual games would show higher variance than your forecast, which would reflect your single best guess of which team is better.  But in reality sometimes Miami will win, sometimes the Spurs will win, by a little, by a lot, etc.   That is a basic principle of forecasting rationality, in other words that actual outcomes should show higher variance than forecasts.  But now consider stocks.  According to Shiller, the “actual results” — namely the realized returns — are the dividends.  The forecasts of the dividends are stock prices.  Yet dividends hardly vary, while stock prices move around a great deal.  It would appear that stock prices violate this variance bounds test because the forecast has a higher variance than the actual outcomes.  (For some push back on this, see the papers by Allan Kleidon from the 1980s.  For non-stationary time series for instance a variance bounds test may not hold because the population variance, as opposed to the sample variance, is infinite and thus undefined.  Another point is that stock prices may move because the stock is an option on the real assets of the firm, which have changing value, whether or not dividends ever vary and of course dividends are consciously smoothed.)

Shiller also extended his variance bounds test to the term structure of interest rates, for instance in his work with John Campbell.  Think of long rates as being forecasts of future short rates.  According to a variance bounds test, the long rates should be less volatile, but in market data we generally observe the opposite.  This again raises the possibility that markets are overreacting to new information rather than estimating values rationally.

You will note that some of Shiller’s models imply systematic returns to betting against the market and expecting some long-run mean reversion.  If the market is overreacting to new information right now, over some longer time horizon it will have to return closer to fundamental values.  So if you, as an investor, have enough patience, you should (on average) bet against short-term market movements.  Of course this hypothesis has received a good deal of empirical testing and perhaps there is some (slight) long run mean reversion, although it is not clear how much those gains can be captured after transactions costs are paid.  In any case, there may be some excess returns to buying right after prices have fallen, contrary to what a strict interpretation of efficient markets theory would suggest.

Shiller’s 1984 piece, “Stock Prices and Social Dynamics,” with Ben Friedman, started laying out a “trends” and “fads” approach to stock and also housing prices.  This integration of psychology and economics might help explain why markets appear to overreact to short-term information.

One intriguing side of Shiller is his advocacy of derivatives and prediction markets to help individuals better hedge risk.  On that see Shiller’s book Finance and the Good Society.  Shiller for instance would like to see explicit futures or forward markets in gdp, and individuals could hedge with those markets to bet against bad business prospects.  One also can imagine laborers insuring their future income by transacting in indicators of economic health.  Shiller has raised the idea of using housing price indices to help hedge against home price risk, whether for future sellers or future buyers.  This aspect of Shiller’s thought has perhaps disappointed some of his fans who have wanted him to take a more critical attitude toward finance.  Shiller instead thinks that a properly reconstituted financial sector could bring the world very significant gains, typically through superior risk hedging.  It remains a general puzzle why so many of these markets continue not to exist, and when they are sometimes started up, they fail to attract sufficient liquidity.

Shiller’s greatest practical contribution is the Case-Shiller housing price index, described by Wikipedia like this:

The Standard & Poor’s Case–Shiller Home Price Indices are repeat-sales house price indices for the United States. There are multiple Case–Shiller home price indices: A national home price index, a 20-city composite index, a 10-city composite index, and twenty individual metro area indices.

This index has become a staple of real world financial analysis and discussion and it is reported in the financial press on a regular basis.

Shiller is also famous for having predicted the housing price bubble which played an important role in America’s Great Recession.  Here is one of his early pieces on that issue.  One of his research innovations was the common sense idea of simply asking home buyers what kind of future price gains they were expecting and then analyzing whether those expectations were realistic (hint: they weren’t).

Here is an on-line course with Shiller, on finance.

Bets and Beliefs

I fear that Tyler’s latest post on bets and beliefs will obfuscate more than clarify. Let’s clarify. There are two questions, do portfolios reveal beliefs? Do bets reveal beliefs?

Tyler has argued that portfolios reveal beliefs. This is false. If transaction costs were zero and there were an asset for every possible future state of the world then this would be true. Since transaction costs are not zero and there are many more states of the world than there are assets–even when we combine assets–portfolios do not reveal beliefs. Portfolios might reveal a few coarse beliefs but otherwise no go. Since most people have lots of beliefs about the future but don’t even have a portfolio (beyond human capital) this should be obvious.

Do bets reveal beliefs? Usually but not necessarily. Two people made bets with Noah Smith. Each thought Noah was an idiot for making the bet. Noah, however, had arbitraged so that he couldn’t lose. Clever Noah! Noah’s bets, either alone or in conjunction, did not reveal his beliefs.  But is this the usual situation? No.

For the same reasons that portfolios don’t reveal beliefs, high transaction costs and few assets relative to states of the world, it’s going to be difficult to arbitrage all bets. Many bets in effect create a new and unique asset that can’t be easily duplicated and arbitraged away in other markets. I once bet Bryan as to what an expert would answer when asked a particular question. Hard to arbitrage that away.

I also agree with Bryan that the question is empirical and not simply theoretical. When I say that a bet is a tax on bullshit the implication is not just that bullshitters are more likely to lose their bets but also that a tax on bullshit reduces its supply. The betting tax causes people to think more carefully and to be more precise. When people are more careful and precise the quality of communication increases. As Adam Ozimek writes:

In a lot of writing in blogs it is unclear specifically what the writer is trying to say, and they seem to wish to convey an attitude about a certain position without actually having to make a particular criticism of it, or by making a much actual narrower criticism than rhetoric implies…It is useful to have betting because deciding clearly resolvable terms of a bet leads to specific claims…

Tyler argues that under some conditions betting won’t change what people say (under a wide range of portfolios…a matter of indifference… bets won’t be authentic) but Tyler doesn’t give us a specific, testable prediction. The empirical evidence, however, is that small bets do cause people to change what they say. This is one of the reasons why even small-bet, prediction markets work well.

Tyler has his reasons for not liking to bet but if you think one of those reasons is that he has already revealed his beliefs then you are surely not a loyal reader.

Why no gdp-indexed bonds?

Might some eurozone nations benefit from gdp-indexed bonds?  Imagine if required bond payments went down when your gdp went down, thereby providing some insurance against bad economic times.  Here is a good summary blog post of the idea.  Here are other writings on the idea.  Alternatively, you might also ask why governments don’t find ways, indirect ways if necessary, to issue equity shares.

Yet we hardly ever see these instruments, although Argentina and Greece have tried what are arguably variants on the idea (pdf.)  Why not?  I can think of a few reasons:

1. Nations might falsify their gdp figures.  Yet I am not sure it is the fundamental reason, since you can imagine the contracts based on more objective gdp correlates, such as prices taken from securities markets or prediction markets.

2. Signaling and adverse selection reasons make large, highly scrutinized entities reluctant to buy explicit, blatant insurance against their own failures.

3. There is no missing market here, because governments could always — either directly or indirectly — short themselves in the CDS market.  See #2 for a caveat.

4. Prosperous and creditworthy nations do not need the bonds, and the less secure nations will encounter costs from splitting the liquidity of their government bonds market.

5. Most governments do not run big budget surpluses in good times, even though they should.  The absence of gdp-linked bonds is a corollary of this failure and the consumption return profiles of those two options are remarkably similar.  In any case if a government has the discipline to forsake cash in good times, to save it up for bad times, as for instance Chile and Norway have shown, savings are easier than the gdp-indexed bonds.  Alternatively a profligate will neither save nor buy insurance.

Most of all, I say #5.

CFTC Cracks Down on Intrade

CFTC Press Release: The U.S. Commodity Futures Trading Commission (CFTC) today filed a civil complaint in federal district court in Washington, DC, charging Intrade The Prediction Market Limited (Intrade) and Trade Exchange Network Limited (TEN), Irish companies based in Dublin, Ireland, with offering commodity option contracts to U.S. customers for trading, as well as soliciting, accepting, and confirming the execution of orders from U.S. customers, all in violation of the CFTC’s ban on off-exchange options trading.

Intrade and TEN jointly operate an online “prediction market” trading website, through which customers buy or sell binary options which allow them to predict (“yes” or “no”) whether a specific future event will occur, according to the CFTC’s complaint.

Specifically, according to the complaint, from September 2007 to June 25, 2012, Intrade and TEN operated an online “prediction market” trading website, which allowed U.S. customers to trade options products prohibited by the CFTC’s ban on off-exchange options trading. Through the website, Intrade and TEN allegedly unlawfully solicited and permitted U.S. customers to buy and sell options predicting whether specific future events would occur, including whether certain U.S. economic numbers or the prices of gold and currencies would reach a certain level by a certain future date, and whether specific acts of war would occur by a certain future date.

…David Meister, the Director of the CFTC’s Division of Enforcement, stated: “It is against the law to solicit U.S. persons to buy and sell commodity options, even if they are called ‘prediction’ contracts, unless they are listed for trading and traded on a CFTC-registered exchange or unless legally exempt. The requirement for on-exchange trading is important for a number of reasons, including that it enables the CFTC to police market activity and protect market integrity. Today’s action should make it clear that we will intervene in the ‘prediction’ markets, wherever they may be based, when their U.S. activities violate the Commodity Exchange Act or the CFTC’s regulations.”

In its continuing litigation the CFTC seeks civil monetary penalties, disgorgement of ill-gotten gains, and permanent injunctions against further violations of federal commodities law, as charged, among other relief.

The CFTC acknowledges the Central Bank of Ireland for its assistance in the CFTC’s investigation of Intrade and TEN.

Intrade announces:

We are sorry to announce that due to legal and regulatory pressures, Intrade can no longer allow US residents to participate in our real-money prediction markets.

Unfortunately this means that all US residents must begin the process of closing down their Intrade accounts. We strongly urge you to begin this process immediately:

What is it that Springsteen says, “Well the cops finally busted Madame Marie for tellin’ fortunes better than they do.”