Month: December 2005

XM Satellite Radio and cultural diversity

Some of the stations have changed:

Out: African music, World music

In: French songs (Sur La Route), and also French rap and other French innovations (La Musique)

This was done to obtain entry into the Canadian market, which among other things required appeasement of the French-language minority.  It is funny what is sometimes done in the name of cultural diversity, eh?  Let’s hope that world music makes a comeback once those horrible Christmas music channels are gone.

More on the Xbox shortage

I’m finishing an MA in Economics at Boston University right now, and am also the author of "PSX: The Guide to the Sony Playstation" which is being released this week.  In the course of research for the book, I interviewed a number of VPs at Sony about why they priced at 299 when the PS2 came out.  The waits for the PS2, in fact, were much longer than those for the Xbox360, and still no rise in prices.

Here’s my understanding of the pricing situation:

1) Console prices are announced months in advance of the system release, unlike many other products.  There is a general consensus that a price above 299 (or 399, perhaps, which is the true price of the 360) will be unsuccessful.  In the mid and late 90s, a huge number of consoles bombed by announcing prices of 400-1000 (Sega Saturn, cd-i, 3DO, Amiga CD32, etc.). Third party developers are essential to a system’s success (a system without games, after all, does nothing), and in order to have games ready for a system, they evaluate a system a year before launch.  A high price would discourage developers -> discourage games -> lessen demand.  Given the competitiveness of the console game market, I have no doubt that major third-party game producers (Activision, Ubisoft, Square, EA, etc.) would balk if Microsoft were to raise prices, fearing, justly or not, that system sales two years down the road (when their games are ready) will be lower. For the 500-pound gorillas (EA in particular) there might even be contractual stipulations with MS about the system price.

The other reason is the one Alex gave – The $700 consoles on ebay represent the highest WTP on the demand curve, not the average.  Personally, I don’t think MS would’ve sold 500k Xboxes at $500.  Why MS didn’t auction off "limited edition" systems early, as you said, remains a mystery though. Nintendo has done exactly that with some items (in charity auctions, however).

In any case, the basic pricing structure is no mystery at all.  MS needs to satisfy both end-users AND third-party developers, not just end-users. They’re selling a *platform* more than a product.

Seasonal advice from the dismal science, Part 2 of 3

Gift-giving advice today…

Do not buy gifts for nieces, nephews or grandchildren. Send money if you must, but other gifts will be spectacularly incompetent. Using questionnaires, the Joel Waldfogel famously revealed (in an article entitled ‘The Deadweight Loss of Christmas’ – JSTOR) that the typical $50 gift is valued at between $35 and $43 by the ungrateful recipient, but that gifts from grandparents, aunts and uncles were even less welcome. If you are content to spend $50 to provide $35 worth of pleasure to your distant relatives, then next time please use me as your middleman.

It’s the thought that counts. His detractors rarely admit this, but Professor Waldfogel explicitly asked his subjects not to consider sentimental value. Sentimental value might indeed outweigh the waste of a poorly-chosen tie, but the cheaper the tie the more likely that is to happen. A $50 tie valued at $40 by the recipient is still a good gift if it also creates $15 worth of warm fuzzy feelings. But think how much better it would be to give a $5 tie valued at $4, which still created the same $15 of fuzzy feelings: this is a much more efficient way to produce a smile.

Actually, maybe it’s better if you don’t give anything at all. Steven Landsburg reminds us that one of Christmas’s greatest philanthropists was Scrooge. His miserly refusal to eat a Christmas turkey, year after year, meant one more turkey that someone else could afford. His capacious bank account meant that money was available to lend out to entrepreneurs and kept interest rates low. There’s nothing wrong with spending money if you’re going to enjoy it, but if it’s going to be frittered away on chintz then you couldn’t ask for a better role-model than Scrooge.

Tomorrow: making those New Year resolutions stick, surviving the sales, and why Alan Greenspan should replace that soft fool Santa Claus.

Do right-wing or left-wing academics have a “narrower tent”?

This paper provides copious results from a 2003 survey of academics. We analyze the responses of 1208 academics from six scholarly associations (in anthropology, economics, history, legal and political philosophy, political science, and sociology) with regard to their views on 18 policy issues. The issues include economic regulations, personal-choice restrictions, and military action abroad. We find that the academics overwhelmingly vote Democratic and that the Democratic dominance has increased significantly since 1970. A multivariate analysis shows strongly that Republican scholars are more likely to land outside of academia. On the 18 policy questions, the Democratic-voter responses have much less variation than do the Republicans. The left has a narrow tent. The Democratic and Republican policy views of academics are somewhat in line with the ideal types, except that across the board both groups are simply more statist than the ideal types might suggest. Regarding disciplinary consensus, we find that the discipline with least consensus is economics. We do a cluster analysis, and the mathematical technique sorts the respondents into groups that nicely correspond to familiar ideological categories: establishment left, progressive, conservative, and libertarian. The conservative group and the libertarian group are equal in size (35 individuals, each), suggesting that academics who depart from the leftist ranks are as likely to be libertarian as conservative. We also find that conservatives are closer to the establishment left than they are to the libertarians.

That is by Daniel Klein and Charlotta Stern, here is the paper.

The Cuban Cigar Mystery

Why are Cuban cigars good?  It’s not as if communist economies are known for producing quality goods so why the exception for Cuban cigars?  I have a few hypotheses:

  1. Cuban cigars are not good.  The contrary impression is due to rememberances of things past and the sex appeal of the forbidden fruit.  (Testable hypothesis: Are Cuban cigars as highly prized in countries where they are not banned?)
  2. The Cuban "terroir," the soil, climate and environment are unique.   (Maybe but Communists destroy good terroir – see Zimbabwe, the Ukraine etc. – all the time.)
  3. Castro puts a huge amount of resources and incentives into producing cigars because a) he likes to smoke and b) exporting cigars and doctors is good for the brand image.  Cuban cigars are like Soviet chess.
  4. Castro has basically privatized the cigar industry allowing for significant market incentives.

Comments are open for those who know more about cigars and the Cuban cigar industry.

Who benefits from fair trade?

…conservative commentator Philip Oppenheim…argued recently that in
Britain, it’s supermarkets that profit most from fair trade sales. They
charge a premium for fair trade bananas, for example, while a
"minuscule sliver ends up with the people the movement is designed to
help"…

Here is more.  In case you don’t know, fair trade sells a product at a premium price, under the promise that the workers are treated better and paid more.  But will that improve living standards?  Hmm…this sounds like a problem in tax incidence theory.  To make the best possible case for fair trade, I will assume the promise of good treatment is credible.

Let’s say the supermarket has some market power and would have liked to price discriminate on coffee sales.  Now you can buy either normal coffee or fair trade coffee, and the richer,
more conscientious people are willing to pay more for the latter.  Some people can be charged lower prices, while others pay higher prices.  Fair trade will likely increase coffee output, relative to a world with no fair trade.  Profits will go up.  But what happens to input prices?  Will wages of Rwandan coffee producers rise?

It depends on the alternative to market segregation.  It is possible that if only a single kind of coffee can be sold, the market would opt for the more expensive coffee, involving better treatment of all workers.  Even if you don’t expect this today, it might happen in a few years’ time.  If McDonald’s can improve the treatment of all the chickens it buys, maybe Starbucks or some other force will force the coffee sector to clean up its act.  So development optimists should be suspicious of fair trade.  It could diminish long-run general progress by giving the conscientious an outlet for their charity.  By splitting up the market, we are institutionalizing especially poor treatment for one class of workers.  Furthermore the high profits from price discrimination imply that
producers will be keen to continue such segregation rather than end it.

How about a genre called "Exploitation Coffee"?  You pay less, and they promise to treat the workers especially poorly.  That wording is a less effective marketing ploy, but that is what quality differentiation and indeed "fair trade" boils down to.

It is well known that price discrimination can either raise or lower the average level of prices, but it does increase price dispersion.  We can expect it to increase wage dispersion as well.  It is harder to predict whether price discrimination will raise or lower wages at the bottom level of the scale. 

By increasing output, fair trade can bid up wages for coffee producers.  But fair trade also diverts some drinkers from Exploitation Coffee.  If the switching effect is large, wages for producers of Exploitation Coffee can fall.  Just as we have created two classes of market prices, so have we created two classes of market wages.  If you believe that coffee producing firms have some degree of monopsony power, this is  sustainable and again will increase profits but possibly worsen human misery for the poorest.

These are all "existence theorems."  I would not be surprised to learn that current benefits from fair trade are positive.  But since I am a development optimist, I have reservations about the institution in the longer run.

Exam question: How much of this analysis also applies to free-range vs. factory-farmed chickens?  Hint: not all of it (why not?)  Comments are open…and might you know of empirical work on how fair trade influences wages?

Seasonal advice from the dismal science, Part 1 of 3

Burn your Christmas card list. Deep down, we all know that many Christmas card exchanges are more like vendettas than expressions of seasonal goodwill. Is your yearly card from former neighbors Mr. and Mrs. Grinch a genuine effort to keep in touch – or does it reflect the fact that they’ll be damned rather than be the first to stop? Thomas Schelling argues for a bankruptcy procedure in which all lists should be burned and people could start again, motivated only by genuine good-will. Take his advice and you’ll be doing yourself a favor, not to mention releasing all those near-strangers you inflict cards upon. (Read more.)

Take your children to a good fire-and-brimstone Christmas service – but make it brief. Robert Barro and Rachel McCleary have investigated the connection between religion and economic growth, with two notable results. First, belief in heaven and hell is good for business, presumably because it generates trust and substitutes for expensive legal proceedings. Second, time spent in church is not time well spent: presumably you make some contacts but could more profitably seek them elsewhere. To ensure successful offspring, send them to a church that instills the fear of God into them without demanding too much face time. Shop around.

Establish firm property rights over the TV remote. I can’t stress this one too much. Ronald Coase taught us that disputes over shared resources can always be resolved, provided the costs of negotiation are low and property rights are clearly established. Arguments only happen because it’s not clear who has the right to name the channel. Therefore, somebody must be given the control of the TV remote and should auction off the right to choose the channel to the highest bidder, perhaps in half-hour slots. It doesn’t matter much who the owner of the remote is – the choice of programming should be the same. Still, in our household I’ve always been in favor of giving the job to the paterfamilias.

Further advice to follow tomorrow.

Contemporary composers blossom late

Among the 20- to 25-year olds, the ones who initially produce the most
professional-sounding music will often be the least original – their
technical polish may be evidence more of a mimetic ability than an
original vision. The more “out there” a composer’s personal vision is,
the more awkward his or her early works will probably sound, and the
longer it will take his or her compositional language to crystallize
into something eloquent and communicative.

The early idioms of many composers testify to this. For instance,
Nancarrow didn’t discover his instrument until age 36, and took another
8 or 10 years to master it. Partch, having an even wider range of
unconventional elements to integrate, was nearly 50 when his style
started to feel compelling. Varése wrote romantic music that he later
abandoned, and struggled to bring his style into focus at just shy of
40. Feldman’s music seemed like a cute adjunct to Cage’s philosophy
until his ambitions suddenly blossomed at age 44. Elliott Carter wrote
an undistinguished neoclassicism into his 40s, and didn’t find what we
recognize as a Carterian idiom until age 43. Rzewski wrote some
charming minimalist works in his early 30s, but didn’t create his own
style until he was 37, with The People United. Robert Ashley was involved in the avant-garde all along, but didn’t begin to stand out until he wrote Perfect Lives at 48. Giacinto Scelsi was 54 when he found what he had been looking for in his 4 pezzi su una nota sola.

Here are my previous posts on age and achievement.

Solving Das XBox Problem

The usual explanation, a shortage generates hype, doesn’t make much sense.  First, as Tim Harford also points out hype can be generated by high prices as well as by shortages.  Very high end luxury items, for example, like Lamborghini’s are difficult to obtain but also very expensive.  Second, it’s implausible that a shortage
now could generate such greater sales later as to be worthwhile this is especially true given that Christmas is the peak selling season.  You want
hype before not during Christmas. 

The Cultural Foundations of Economics

Here is a new paper on culture and economics, destined for the Journal of Economic Perspectives, hat tip to the New Economist blog.

Imagine economics is no longer built around the dual of preferences and constraints.  We would instead have the following starting points:

1. Priors.  Without differing Bayesian priors, there is neither trade nor disagreement.  Your priors depend on your cultural background.

2. Beliefs. What model of the economy — and more importantly of yourself — lurks in your mind?

3. Peers. Which people do you accept as your relevant peer group?  This often determines the working model for your beliefs.

4. Stories. What stories do you tell yourself about who you are?

Arguably these analytical categories are more fundamental to human behavior than utility maximization.  Combine them with evolutionary biology, and a bit of neuroscience, a marriage with sociology and social psychology, and we have the foundations for a revolution in economic science.  Fifty years or so from now, that is.