More evidence on immigration and wages
The best of current investigations continue to support the conclusion that immigration does not hurt American real wages. Here is part of the abstract from a recent NBER working paper:
Because U.S. and foreign born workers belong to different skill groups that are imperfectly substitutable, one needs to articulate a production function that aggregates different types of labor (and accounts for complementarity and substitution effects) in order to calculate the various effects of immigrant labor on U.S.-born labor. We introduce such a production function, making the crucial assumption that U.S. and foreign-born workers with similar education and experience levels may nevertheless be imperfectly substitutable, and allowing for endogenous capital accumulation. This function successfully accounts for the negative impact of the relative skill levels of immigrants on the relative wages of U.S. workers. However, contrary to the findings of previous literature, overall immigration generates a large positive effect on the average wages of U.S.-born workers. We show evidence of this positive effect by estimating the impact of immigration on both average wages and housing values across U.S. metropolitan areas (1970-2000). We also reproduce this positive effect by simulating the behavior of average wages and housing prices in an open city-economy, with optimizing U.S.-born agents who respond to an inflow of foreign-born workers of the size and composition comparable to the immigration of the 1990s.
Here is my previous post on the topic; try this one too.
How do feelings of mortality change your behavior?
Randall Parker has the scoop. Here is one excerpt, quoted by Randall:
…when confronted with thoughts of death, people tend to act in ways that will boost their self-esteem. They also have fewer cognitive resources to resist behaviors that are not central to their self-image. People for whom being slim or fit is important to their self-image, for instance, will not be as likely to overeat, but if physical appearance isn’t as important, the willpower to resist that fudge sundae will plummet.
Here is my previous post, with an assist from Robin Hanson, on the same topic. Let me note in passing, this is one reason why I would expect a bimodal response to a major crisis such as avian flu. Most people will behave quite heroically; those who take pride in being social rebels/misfits will act like scoundrels.
Facts about Thomas Schelling
1. Jorgen Weibull — who does evolutionary game theory — chaired the committee this year. Addendum: Here is the full list of wise men, thanks to Dennis Josefsson for the pointer.
2. If you wanted to see much of Tom, you had to agree to meet with him on Saturday mornings. This was my preferred time too.
3. Before The Strategy of Conflict, game theory was for the most part an abstract desert. It is not easy to find concrete economic propositions in von Neumann and Morgenstern or for that matter in Nash. Tom brought game theory into the real world. The magnitude of this shift is hard to appreciate from the vantage point of today.
4. Schelling’s early research was on open economy macroeconomics.
5. He loves Bach, and The Art of the Fugue in particular, most of all the Grigory Sokolov version. This is indeed a desert island set of discs.
What did this Prize mean?
Yes it is Thomas Schelling and Robert Aumann, wonderful picks.
The Nobel website says: "for having enhanced our understanding of conflict and cooperation through game-theory analysis." Here is the NYT article, no permalink yet. FoxNews offers similar information. Both men clearly deserve the prize. I view this year’s award as a welcome swing back to the philosophical, theoretical, and speculative dimensions of economics. In recent years the Committee seems to have gone out of its way to reward the scientistic approach to economics (Heckman and McFadden, for instance). All these earlier picks were good ones, but I am happy to see Schelling — a fruitful generalist if there ever was one — and Aumann, a deeply philosophical thinker, get the nod. Aumann I don’t know personally, but there are few scholars I admire more than Thomas Schelling.
Robert Aumann, one of two new Nobel Laureates
Here is one summary of Aumann’s work on game theory:
Robert J. Aumann’s has been one of the leading figures in the mathematical surge that has characterized Neo-Walrasian economics and game theory in the past forty years. Aumann entered into economics via cooperative game theory –
In Neo-Walrasian theory, Robert Aumann is perhaps best known for his theory of core equivalence in a "continuum" economy. Aumann introduced measure theory into the analysis of economies with an infinite number of agents – formalizing the "perfectly competitive" scenario. In his classical 1964 paper, Aumann proved the equivalence of the Edgeworthian core and Walrasian equilibrium allocations when there are an uncountable infinite number of agents – thereby providing the limit case for future work on core convergence. In order to prove this result was not vacuous, Aumann went on to prove the existence of equilibrium (1966) in this "perfectly competitive" scenario. On his way, he contributed to mathematics itself by providing a definition of the "integral" of a correspondence (1965), which was previously absent.
Previously, Aumann (1962) had swung Ockham’s razor and helped remove the axiom of completeness of preferences from the Walrasian theory of choice. In another classical paper with F.J. Anscombe in 1964, Aumann formalized the notion of "subjective probability", a concept that had been earlier forwarded by Leonard Savage, that profoundly changed the theory of choice under uncertainty.
His contributions to game theory have perhaps been no less path-breaking. Aumann entered game theory in 1959 to carefully distinguish between infinitely and finitely repeated games. With Bezalel Peleg in 1960, Aumann formalized the notion of a coalitional game without transferable utility (NTU) – one of the organizing beacons of his later research. With Michael Maschler (1963), he introduced the concept of a "bargaining set". In 1974, Aumann went on to identify "correlated equilibrium" in Bayesian games. In 1975, Aumann went on to prove a convergence theorem for the Shapley value. In 1976, he formally defined the concept of "Common Knowledge". Also in 1976, in an unpublished paper with Lloyd Shapley, Aumann provided the perfect folk theorem using the limit of means criterion.
Here is a strange but fascinating interview with Aumann. It covers John Nash, religion, and the Cold War, among other matters. Here is his home page, with links to articles.
My favorite Aumann paper is his 1976 piece on agreeing to disagree. He proved the startling result that if two rational, truth-seeking people have common "priors," in a Bayesian sense rigorously definable, then those two individuals should not disagree once they exchange opinions. Imagine I think there are 200 balls in the urn, but Robin Hanson thinks there are 300 balls in the urn. Once Robin tells me his estimate, and I tell him mine, we should converge upon a common opinion. In essence his opinion serves as a "sufficient statistic" for all of his evidence. (This analysis also led Aumann to clarify the important game-theoretic concept of "common knowledge.") Yet people disagree all the time. Does this mean that priors are rarely common? That we are rarely rational truth-seekers? A bit of both? Robin Hanson is doing much work on this topic. Here is my paper with Robin, we argue you that if you disagree with your "epistemic peers," you are probably not a truth-seeker.
Congratulations to both Aumann and Schelling, comments are open…
Thomas Schelling, new Nobel Laureate
Note my biases, Schelling was my mentor at Harvard.
Tom is an unassuming guy, who looks as if he sells Hush Puppies at the local mall. But he is one of the sharpest people you will meet. He delivers the killer point, argument, or anecdote with striking regularity. Even in his eighties he is sharp as a tack. He has a deeply philosophical and humanistic approach to economics. What are his contributions?
1. The idea of precommitment. You can be better off, either individually, or institutionally, if your choices are limited in advance. This is a key idea in monetary policy (many governments seek to tie the hands of their central banks), the theory of bargaining (try buying a used car, and see if the salesman doesn’t talk about "the boss upstairs"), and industrial organization (firms may invest in capacity to precommit a market position and deter rivals). You find the precommitment frequently in movies as well, especially where kidnapping is involved; what is that Mel Gibson flick again? Here is an excellent Jon Elster piece on the ambiguities of precommitment. Here is my piece on similar themes.
2. The paradox of nuclear deterrence. Ever see Dr. Strangelove? Tom developed the idea that deterrence is never fully credible (why retaliate once you are wiped out?). The best deterrent might involve precommitment, some element of randomness, or a partly crazy leader. I recall Tom telling me he was briefly an advisor to Kubrick. Here is someone else’s essay on the paradox of deterrence.
3. Focal points. People coordinate by directing their attention to commonly recognized points of importance. If a meeting time for lunch is not specified, you might assume 12 noon. If someone mentions "economics blog," of course MarginalRevolution.com comes to mind. And so on. Much social coordination occurs in this manner. I once asked me class: "If you had to hide a one hundred dollar bill in a book, so that your friend would find it, but you could not announce the book, which volume should you choose?" Many said The Bible but of course the game theorist picks Schelling’s The Strategy of Conflict.
4. Behavioral economics and the theory of self-constraint. One of Tom’s best pieces is "The Mind as a Consuming Organ," American Economics Review, 1984. Here is a lecture of his on self control. Will Wilkinson cites a bit of that essay. Tom made it respectable for economists to talk once again about happiness.
Tom has been an underrecognized father of behavioral economics. His work on addiction, memory, and personal control was pathbreaking and came nearly twenty years before the "behavioral revolution" in economics. He analyses the tricks people use to control their wills. For Tom, self-control is often a more important determinant of happiness than is wealth. Tom once told me his work sprung from his own attempts to quit smoking, which he did finally manage. Several times.
5. The economics of segregation. Tom showed how communities can end up segregated even when no single individual cares to live in a segregated neighborhood. Under the right conditions, it only need be the case that the person does not want to live as a minority in the neighborhood, and will move to a neighborhood where the family can be in the majority. Try playing this game with white and black chess pieces, I bet you will get to segregation pretty quickly. Here is a demo model for playing the game.
6. Later in his life Tom turned his attention to issues of global warming. He has been skeptical of the idea that global warming involves insuperably high economic costs. Here is a short essay by Tom on the topic. Here is his excellent AER piece on the same topic.
Tom is not well-represented on the web, here is one photo, but the associated links are mostly broken. Here is Tom’s piece on Hiroshima. Here is the Wikipedia bio, note Wikipedia already reports he won the prize. Here is a great interview with Tom. Here is Tom’s work on the Copenhagen Consensus.
A few bio facts: Like so many other prestigious American economists, Tom worked for the Marshall Plan in its early stages. He spent most of his career at Harvard, first in the economics department, later in the Kennedy School. He had close ties with the Rand Corporation. He was an advisor to Kissinger during the Vietnam War but quit in disgust. He is now emeritus at University of Maryland. I have always interpreted Tom’s political views as those of a conservative Democrat.
Here is a piece I wrote with Dan Klein and Timur Kuran, Salute to Schelling: Keeping it Human. In this piece, recently published, we asked the Committee to give the Prize to Tom. Here are Tom’s books, they are all worth reading.
Comments are open, you can add more; Tom could have won more than one Nobel Prize for all his contributions.
Schelling and Aumann!
I am thrilled! I am just off the airport, I’m giving a talk at Carnegie-Mellon so this will be brief, but the thing to know about Schelling is that he is brilliant but you won’t find hardly a single equation in his Nobel prize winning work. Everyone can and should read the Strategy of Conflict and Micromotives and Macrobehaviour. More later. I expect to be on NPRs All Things Considered this afternoon.
The FedEx Economy
I nominate David Leonhardt for a Voxy for his NYTimes article, the FedEx Economy. Leonhardt opens with a description of how FedEx flies a small fleet of empty planes through the night just waiting for a possible shock that they can rush in to smooth. Sometimes it’s a shock to demand (an unusually large number of packages) other times it’s a shock to supply (a broken plane), in either case FedEx adjusts quickly to restore it’s economy to normal flow.
Project FedEx’s ability onto thousands of other firms, argues Leonhardt, and you have a much more flexible economy with an interesting new feature, "the micro-recession."
When of them strikes, activity slows for a few weeks, sometimes in just certain sectors, as companies adjust to a dip in demand. It has happened much more often in the last few years than in earlier expansions, but growth has picked up each time, thanks in part to adjustments that businesses have made…Year to year, the economy is less volatile but in some ways it has become more volatile month to month.
It’s not clear to me that more flexibility implies more micro-recessions, I’d like to see a model with that feature. It’s also unclear to me how much credit the Fed should get for avoiding big shocks and how much FedEx should get (i.e. technological change). Nevertheless, Leonhardt’s article is a big thought piece on the macroeconomy that one rarely sees in a newspaper.
Lawsuits vs. regulation
Is this left-wing fantasy or unpleasant truth?
Roughly speaking, most European countries have adopted a regulatory model in order to keep corporate abuse in check. There are drawbacks to this model, but it does result in relatively few lawsuits. Conversely, in the United States, business-friendly conservatives have fought to keep regulation light. This often leaves lawsuits, which are inevitably less predictable and more arbitrary than regulation, as the only avenue that ordinary citizens have for checking corporate abuse.
But Geoghegan points out that it’s not just inadequate regulation that has led to the rise in torts. It’s also the demise of unions. In the past, he says, employee grievances from unionized workers were mostly handled via arbitration, which is quick and easy. But with arbitration mostly gone, largely replaced by a mass of confusing and poorly enforced civil rights legislation, the only remedy an employee has if she’s unjustly fired is a lawsuit, and this is fundamentally a more scorched-earth process than old style arbitration…
Is the Vioxx decision in fact the best argument for the FDA? Should we move, as Alex has suggested, to make FDA-approved drugs immune from such lawsuits? Can we precommit to taking certain actions out of the legal nexus in this fashion? File this one under "Top Ten Topics I Wish People Would Study More."
Here is Kevin Drum’s full post and review. Addendum: Here is Jane Galt’s excellent response, read it.
Is globalization changing how we eat?
There is now a French translation of this public address I gave to the International Association of Culinary Professionals. If you have not already read it, here is the original talk in English.
California Fact of the Day
Gov. Arnold Schwarzenegger signed legislation on Friday to outlaw the sale to teenagers of electronic games featuring reckless mayhem and explicit sexuality.
Here is the full story.
Future Nobel Prize winners
Steve Levitt found this list on a blackboard at University of Chicago. I’m still predicting (as opposed to expecting) Eugene Fama and Richard Thaler for this year’s prize. Laugh at me when I am wrong, this coming Monday.
Prediction markets for the flu
In many asset markets the very phenomenon of market trading appears to increase volatility. Richard Roll did some empirical studies of exogenously determined market closings (occasionally various exchanges have closed for brief periods for purely technical reasons, such as catching up on paperwork or upgrading systems). Price volatility was higher across periods when markets where open than when markets where shut. In essence you draw inferences from watching other people trade, other people draw inferences from your inferences, and so on. The “dialogue” embedded in the market makes the price bounce around, even when it hones in on a better mean forecast.
Note further that most meta-rational people should not trade (economists refer to no-trade theorems). When you trade, you should always ask why you think you know more than the person you are trading with. Not every trader in the market as a whole can meta-rationally conclude that she knows more than the other traders. Yes you might trade for liquidity to put your kids through college, but I suspect that most trading in prediction markets is or would be opinion-based. It is especially prone to hubris and irrationality, which again contributes to volatility.
Here is the paradox. We need volume for the price to tell of much about market conditions. But volume is based on irrationality to large extent. Most people — the uninformed — should simply park their money about forget about active trading. And the remaining informed cannot so easily trade against each other.
Prediction markets may be least well-suited for predicting terrorist attacks. Tracking an excessively volatile price could create worry and perhaps sometimes panic. What will happen each time the market price spikes for a nuclear bomb going off in a major American city?
The very virtue of prediction markets now becomes their cost. If you hear rumors, in the absence of prediction markets, you can ignore them and pretend they are not true. With asset markets, however, your forecast moves into equality with that of the market, otherwise you would trade. It is precisely this “forcing quality” that makes prediction markets so useful, but also so potent. Price movements are materially and psychologically harder to ignore. The very feature of prediction markets that mobilizes information also mobilizes coordinated social reactions to the embodied information, and not always for the better.
So the prediction market skeptics have a valid point in some contexts, but this does not detract from the benefits of prediction markets more generally.
I welcome the Ubermensch
There is a great scene in the movie Gattaca of a piano recital. (As I remember it). As we listen to the beautiful and complex music the camera slowly pans in on the pianist’s fast-moving fingers until we see why the music is so amazing, the pianist has six fingers on each hand. Was the music written for the pianist or was the pianist written for the music? Even though Gattaca is often understood as a dystopia the movie is great at showing the promise of genetic engineering.
In India, genetic mutation has done what we are close to doing with genetic engineering. Devender Harne has six fingers on each hand and six toes on one foot and seven on the other. He says the extra fingers let him work faster than other children.
If you think the photo has been Photoshopped, it hasn’t. See here for the full story and video. Thanks to J-Walk Blog for the link.
My favorite things Tennessee
Music: Who is really from Tennessee? Putting the Sun Records and Nashville crowds aside and focusing on birth, you have Lester Flatt, Dolly Parton, Tina Turner, and Aretha Franklin. Honorable mention to Chet Atkins and Isaac Hayes. Add in Bessie Smith and yes I enjoy Justin Timberlake too. Brownie McGee and Sleepy John Estes round out the blues representation. A strong category, and if you count "recorded in Tennessee," it hits the stratosphere.
Elvis Presley song: (Marie’s the Name) His Latest Flame.
Author: James Agee, Let us Now Praise Famous Men. Tennessee Williams does not fit, despite his name. There is not much to choose from here.
Film, set in: Here is a list, but I don’t much like Nashville or The Coal Miner’s Daughter. How about the final scene of Goldfinger?
Director: Quentin Tarantino. He is overrated but Reservoir Dogs is a classic.
Artist: Robert Ryman, here is one image, and no need to write and tell me this is ridiculous. Red Grooms is an alternative pick. There is William Edmondson, if you wish to go the "Outsider" route.
Comments are open…