Month: January 2025
AI-driven hotel planned for Las Vegas
A new, AI-driven hotel is getting set to open in Las Vegas, highlighted by a major presence at CES.
Philippe Ziade, CEO and founder of Growth Holdings, developer of the hotel, detailed the concept as we sat at the CES Otonomus booth display to discuss the venture.
“This is the first truly AI-powered hotel,” said Ziade. “The whole floor is interconnected.”
…The entire focus at the hotel is capturing and leveraging data.
“We create a virtual copy of the guest,” said Ziade. “There is an onboarding before coming to the hotel. We capture information and use AI to scrape the internet and then we track behavior while on property.”
Each guest would have a virtual assistant, which would track and retain that guest’s preferences, which could then be used for subsequent hotel stays.
Ziade said the Las Vegas property is the prototype hotel before national and global expansion of the concept to other locations, such as Dubai…
Due to the large number of variables, such as room sizes, locations, proximity and comfort features, the system is tuned to mix and match the features based on the perceived preferences of the coming hotel guest.
Does it know I want a lot of chargers, thin pillows, and lights that are easy to turn off at night? Furthermore the shampoo bottle should be easy to read in the shower without glasses. Maybe it knows now! Here is the full story, via the excellent Samir Varma.
The sick leave culture that is German
Germans are the “world champions in sick leave”, according to the head of the country’s biggest insurer, who was criticised for demanding that workers without a doctor’s note are unpaid for their first day off.
With the economy slowing and the welfare system under pressure, Germany can ill afford its average per worker of 20 sick days a year, said Oliver Bäte, the chief executive of Allianz SE. The EU average is eight.
The figure of 20 days, based on research by the health insurer DAK, puts a further dent in Germany’s ailing work ethic reputation. Last April, Christian Lindner, then finance minister, admitted that the French, Italians and other nationalities worked “a lot more than we do”, after OECD data showed Germans put in significantly fewer working hours per year than their EU and British neighbours…
“In countries like Switzerland and Denmark people work a month longer per year on average — with comparable pay,” he pointed out.
Here is more from the Times of London. If you can get through the gate, you will see it is Mexico that is the work ethic country.
Thursday assorted links
1. How Japanese architecture adjusted to earthquakes.
2. Was the Berghisel ski jump the most significant building of 2002?
3. How long does it take to get approval for prescribed burns in California?
4. Why the space community should care about Arctic geopolitics: “Any satellite in a polar or sun-synchronous orbit, such as those in critical communications, imagery and weather monitoring constellations, requires an Arctic ground station for consistent tracking, telemetry, and control throughout every revolution.”
5. Is this the beginning of the end for fire insurance in California?
Martha
Martha (Netflix): A compelling bio on Martha Stewart. Her divorce from Andrew Stewart happened more than 30 years ago so the intensity of her anger and bitterness comes as a surprise. With barely concealed rage, she recounts his affairs and how poorly he treated her. “But didn’t you have an affair before he did?” asks the interviewer. “Oh, that was nothing,” she replies waving it off, “nothing.”
Stewart’s willpower and perfectionism are extraordinary. She becomes the U.S.’s first self-made female billionaire after taking her company public in 1999. Then comes the insider trading case. The amount in question was trivial—she avoided a $45,673 loss by selling her ImClone stock early. Stewart was not an ImClone insider and not guilty of insider trading. However, in a convoluted legal twist, she was charged with attempting to manipulate her own company’s stock price by publicly denying wrongdoing in the ImClone matter. Ultimately, she was convicted of lying to the SEC. It’s worth a slap on the wrist but the lead prosecutor is none other than the sanctiminous James Comey (!) and she gets 5 months in prison.
Despite losing hundreds of millions of dollars and control of her own company, Martha doesn’t give up and in 2015, now in her mid 70s, she creates a new image and a new career starting with, of all things, a shockingly hard-assed roast of Justin Bieber. The Bieber roast leads to a succesful colloboration with Snoop Dogg. Legendary.
Stewart is as compelling a figure as Steve Jobs or Elon Musk. Not entirely likable, perhaps, but undeniably admirable.
Claims about fires?
In 2007 the Sierra Club successfully sued the Forest Service to prevent them from creating a Categorical Exclusion (CE) to NEPA for controlled burns (the technical term is “fuel reduction”). The CE would have allowed the forest service to conduct burns without having to perform a full EIS (the median time for which is 3.5 years). See: caselaw.findlaw.com/court/us-9th-c John Muir project helped to claw back the full scope of Categorial Exclusions from the 2018 Omnibus Bill as well (though some easement did make it through). In 2021 the outgoing Trump BLM was served with the following notice of intent to sue by the Center for Biological Diversity for their fuel reduction plan in the Great Basin: biologicaldiversity.org/programs/publi BLM backed away from the plan after the transition. These are specific cases, but the cumulative outcome is that CA state agencies don’t even try it because they know they’ll be sued.
Some of the latter part is exaggerated, here is o1 pro commentary.
In California it is apparently illegal to price fire insurance according to risk? o1 pro seems a bit off on this question, but I think you can read between the lines.
Which are the best analyses you are seeing?
My Conversation with the excellent Scott Sumner
Here is the audio, video, and transcript. Here is the episode summary:
Scott joins Tyler to discuss what reading Depression-era newspapers revealed about Hitler’s rise, when fiat currency became viable, why Sweden escaped the worst of the 1930s crash, whether bimetallism ever made sense, where he’d time-travel to witness economic history, what 1920s Hollywood movies get wrong about their era, how he developed his famous maxim “never reason from a price change,” whether the Fed can ever truly follow policy rules like NGDP targeting, if Congress shapes monetary policy more than we think, the relationship between real and nominal shocks, his favorite Hitchcock movies, why Taiwan’s 90s cinema was so special, how Ozu gets better with age, whether we’ll ever see another Bach or Beethoven, how he ended up at the University of Chicago, what it means to be a late bloomer in academia, and more.
And an excerpt:
COWEN: If the Fed had listened to you during the great financial crisis, what would have been the rate of price inflation in 2009, roughly?
SUMNER: I think it would have been a little bit higher than the Fed’s target, but not a lot higher.
COWEN: Say real GDP was going to fall by 2 percent.
SUMNER: You see, that’s what I don’t accept. See, I believe that the fall in real GDP was mostly due to the fall in nominal GDP. We know that the trend rate of growth in nominal GDP had been 5 percent a year going into the slump, and it fell to -3. It’s like an eight-point decline in the growth rate. Now, in a counterfactual where they keep nominal GDP growing at 5 percent a year, let’s say, most of the difference shows up in stronger real growth, and only a small part of the difference shows up in higher inflation. The inflation rate in 2009 was actually around zero. It might have been no more than 2 percent or 3 percent, if nominal growth had been that much higher. Real growth might have been 5 percent higher.
COWEN: This is a point where I think I disagree with you, even though I agree with much of what you’ve said up until now. I worry that by attributing the decline in real GDP to a decline in nominal GDP, that it’s on the verge of being tautologous. Not a literal tautology, given prices don’t move that much — that you’re explaining a thing by itself, and I think it would have been quite possible for real GDP to fall by a few percent.
If we had stabilized the growth path of nominal GDP, we would have had price inflation of, say, 5 percent, which I would have greatly preferred to what we did, to be clear. I think it’s one reason why central banks are reluctant to institute your kind of advice, because they know they’ll be blamed for a price inflation rate of 5 percent. Do you see what I’m saying?
SUMNER: I see what you’re saying, but I think that, in a way, your instincts that it’s almost tautological reflect the fact that you sort of buy into what I’m saying about the interrelationship between real and nominal shocks. We both know that they’re not necessarily at all closely correlated, right? In 2008 and 2009, Zimbabwe had a recession and a hyperinflation at the same time. Their nominal and real economies are going in dramatically different directions. We also know that real and nominal variables are radically different variables.
When our instincts tell us that there’s something tautological about the correlation between real and nominal GDP in the United States, it’s because our instincts have recognized the fact that, in fact, most of the US business cycle is due to nominal shocks interacting with sticky wages. If that hypothesis is true, that model of the business cycle is true for the United States but not for Zimbabwe, then what it’s telling us is that if we can control nominal GDP growth, probably the path of real GDP will also be more stable.
Now, it’s possible that we do succeed in stabilizing nominal GDP growth, and we find out it doesn’t help. But there’s an awful lot of circumstantial evidence to support my claim, because we observe, for instance, in the United States that when nominal GDP is more volatile, so is real GDP. That’s one thing we know. We also know that some of the volatility of nominal GDP comes from very clear monetary policy mistakes that have been made at various periods of time that can be clearly identified.
When we see this show up in similar movements in real output, there’s just a strong presumption that there’s a causal relationship there. Financial markets also seem to treat it like there’s a causal relationship. Financial market responses to Federal Reserve policy shocks seem to reflect a view in the financial markets that these things are important for the real economy.
COWEN: I think my view would be, when you get a very bad recession, it’s typically the combination of negative nominal shocks and significant negative real shocks, often to credit markets. The negative real shocks are not just an epiphenomenon or result of the nominal problem mixed with sticky wages. You have both happening, and the credit market problems don’t just go away if you do your nominal job. Then you get back to these situations where you’ll need a fairly high rate of price inflation to stabilize the growth path of nominal GDP.
You just think credit market shocks are not that important? Like what Charles Kindleberger wrote, you wouldn’t really agree with that economic history? Or how should I frame your view here?
And on cinema and the arts:
SUMNER: Well, there was — I can’t get the quote right exactly, but Susan Sontag said something to the effect of, “Are artistic masterpieces still possible?” Then she said, “Or are we not receptive to the possibility of future masterpieces?” Is the problem they’re not being produced, or that we’re no longer receptive to them? I think it is somewhat of an open question. You can consume so much of any art form, or multiple art forms, that you become a bit jaded.
I don’t know, it would be interesting to think about what younger viewers that are very talented at the arts think of directors like, say, Kubrick as compared to how I view Kubrick. I saw the Kubrick films when they first came out, but he has been very much imitated. So maybe younger viewers would be less impressed by some of his films because they would think, “Well, I’ve seen that before.” Of course, what they saw before was actually after he created that innovative style.
We just have so much material flooding our senses that it may be more difficult. Like, could you imagine someone coming along like Bach or Beethoven in classical music in the next decade and having that impact? Wouldn’t you agree it’s unlikely we’ll get something like that?
Self-recommending, I also liked the part at the very end.
Addendum: Here is commentary from Scott on the CWT.
My podcast with Yascha Mounk
Here is one description:
Yascha Mounk and Tyler Cowen discuss the likely economic futures of Europe, Asia, and Africa; how the United States should approach competition with China; and what role young people should ascribe to personal financial advancement in their career choices.
Here is the Apple link. Transcript here.
Wednesday assorted links
1. Martin Wolf on India and Singh (FT).
2. Britain has lost about one-third of its hedgehogs since 2000.
3. The woman who repairs the ASML machines (WSJ).
4. Traits that will cease to be valuable — good post, though I do not agree with each and every claim.
5. Canadian throat singing. And from Siberia.
6. Bio cell and immunology claims.
7. AEA is now absurdly woke, and at just the wrong time. I suspect they are too locked in to backpedal anytime soon. Embarrassing.
8. In this study, a one percent increase in housing supply lowers rents by 0.19%.
9. Italian village forbids its residents from becoming seriously ill.
10. Do we need congestion taxes and birth control for wild animals?
Nuclear Deregulation
Nuclear deregulation. Yes, I know how that sounds but bear with me. As Koopman and Dourado write in the WSJ:
The Atomic Energy Act of 1954 established a precise framework for nuclear regulation, requiring federal licensing only for facilities that either use nuclear material “in such quantity as to be of significance to the common defense and security” or use it “in such manner as to affect the health and safety of the public.” This careful distinction recognized that not every nuclear reactor poses meaningful risks.
Those qualifiers were intentional but for a long time were unimportant because nuclear reactors were big and potentially quite dangerous but that was 70 years ago! Today, there are small, safe nuclear reactor designs which meet the requirements of the 1954 Act.
Small modular reactors are dramatically different from the massive reactors envisioned during the Cold War. The reactors at issue in this case generate a fraction of the power of conventional nuclear plants—around 20 megawatts or less—and are designed with modern safety features that would release close to zero radiation even in a worst-case meltdown scenario. Last Energy’s design operates entirely inside a container with 12-inch steel walls that has no credible mode of radioactive release even in the worst reasonable scenario.
Even in such a scenario, according to the plaintiffs, radiation exposure would be less than a tenth what the NRC has deemed too safe to require regulation in other contexts—and less than 1/800th of a routine abdominal CT scan.
The NRC should not be regulating these reactors. Small scale nuclear should be regulated like x-Ray machines or gas turbines not like billion dollar nuclear power plants, the current rule. Reasonable regulation will allow iterative innovation. As I sais in my post Give Innovation a Chance, innovation is a dynamic process. You must build to build better.
Yet the NRC is stifling this progress. The licensing process alone can take up to nine years. Small modular reactor company NuScale spent more than $500 million just to get its design certification approved by the NRC, a process that took more than two million hours of labor and required millions of pages of information. NuScale still needs to apply for its license, which will multiply these costs.
The NRC rule is currently being challenged in State of Texas v. U.S. Nuclear Regulatory Commission. I think the case has a good chance of winning which would be a wonderful win for energy abundance.
Evolving Returns to Personality
Weanalyze trends in labor-market returns to psychological traits using data from half a million Finnish men from 2001 to 2015. Cognitive skills’ value declined, while noncognitive skills’ value increased. Our novel findings show that extraversion drives this rise, while conscientiousness remains stable. Extraversion’s rising returns are most pronounced for lower earners and those on the employment margin. These traits predict different labor market paths: extraversion predicts lower education and more work experience, while cognitive ability and conscientiousness lead to higher education and high-paying jobs.
That is from a recent paper by Ramin Izadi and Joonas Tuhkuri.
One early report on congestion pricing in NYC
That is my latest Bloomberg column, here is one bit:
The core version of the plan stipulates a $9 toll for drivers entering Manhattan below and including 60th Street. Implementation is by E-Z Pass, and the tolls can vary in complex ways. But if you don’t cross the line, you don’t pay. So residents below 60th Street are exempt, provided they stay within the zone.
And:
The data do indicate some effective immediate adjustments. Most notably, morning commutes through the major bridges and tunnels into Manhattan have eased. Presumably the tolls have discouraged some drivers whose trips were less important to them, leading to quicker travel times for those drivers willing to pay. Economists typically consider such changes to be an improvement.
Such changes, however, aren’t of much help to native New Yorkers, in particular those living inside the zone. The earliest measurements indicate that traffic within the zone has not eased notably. So far, I would say the biggest beneficiaries of the policy are the wealthier residents of New Jersey and the New York state government, which is now set to take in more revenue.
Whatever you think of those consequences — YMMV, as they say — at least there is now actual data to sift through. You can track it here, and again it is important to stress that these preliminary assessments may change with time.
Many Manhattanites supported the charges on the grounds that they wanted a quieter, cleaner, less congested center city that was more friendly to bicycles and pedestrians. Think of Copenhagen or Amsterdam, if you have ever been. What they may end up getting is a central city more friendly to their cars — and less friendly to outsiders. It remains to be seen if central Manhattan has a path to becoming truly pleasant in the Nordic sense.
I will continue to follow this issue, as new results will be coming in. Of course stiff tolls on those living inside the zone were the correct thing to do. But that is not how politics works.
What should I ask Ross Douthat?
Ross has a new (and very good) book coming out Believe: Why Everyone Should be Religious. I will be doing a Conversation with him, mostly about the book although not entirely. Here is my first and second Conversation with Ross. Here is my earlier exchange with Ross about belief in God, scroll back through the links.
So what should I ask him?
Tuesday assorted links
3. Abbey Road console markets in everything.
4. Salim Furth and Matt Bruenig on congestion pricing and tax incidence theory. True or false?
5. Jon Hartley podcast with Myron Scholes.
6. Carl Menger’s granddaughter is still alive, and speaks to us about her grandfather.
7. Surviving in cashless China?
8. Indian mom and son cover Radiohead’s Creep.
10. The Simon-Ehrlich resource price bet, over different decades.
11. “The fact checkers have just been too politically biased.” Nice watch!
Another hypothesis why building aesthetics have declined in quality
I have been reading Coby Lefkowitz’s Building Optimism: Why Our World Looks the Way It Does, and How to Make it Better. I am most interested in chapter five “Why Does Everywhere Look the Same?” That is another way of restating the puzzle that, at some point after WWII, the aesthetic quality of a lot of buildings and neighborhoods seemed to plummet. Even though we are much wealthier today.
With increasing returns to scale, we produce these buildings and neighborhoods en masse, and although they are comfortable and affordable, they just aren’t that pretty. Quite simply they are mass produced.
The increasing returns to scale hypothesis explains a few facts:
1. Why we find this trend almost everywhere.
2. Why there are some exceptions to the trend in striking individual buildings (Guggenheim Bilbao?), but very few exceptions on larger scales involving many buildings together.
3. Why the trend does not end.
4. Why interiors can be so lovely when exteriors are so mediocre. The interior of course is very often “created” by the individual family living there, rather than bought en masse.
By no means is the increasing returns to scale hypothesis for mediocre buildings entirely new. You can find versions of it in many other writers. But perhaps Lefkowitz states it the most clearly?
Should America privatize the postal service?
That is the topic of my latest Bloomberg column, here is one bit:
But Poles did not privatize everything. They generally left water companies and electricity providers in the public sector, for example. This is the second category of privatizations: those that are uncertain in their impact.
Water and electricity are two essential services where there is no easy way to get privatization exactly right. It is simply impractical to have many firms selling the product to a single group of households — not in the same way that, say, many cow farmers can produce and sell cheese. It costs too much to lay the basic piping or wires.
One option is to have a private entity with monopoly privileges but regulated prices. Another is to have a set of “common carrier” wires and allow multiple producers to use the network on regulated terms of access. A third is just to have the government own and run the company.
Involving the private sector may give better incentives for cost reduction as well as innovation, since profit maximization is a strong impetus for those kinds of improvements. The efficiency of the private company, however, is also a source of problems. A private company may be efficient at lobbying the government for cronyist privileges. That may lead to higher prices, overly generous reimbursement for cost increases, tougher barriers to entry, or entrenched technologies that favor the incumbent.
In other words: If embedded in an imperfect system, corporate efficiency is not always a pure virtue.
In the US, privately owned and publicly owned water utilities show, on average, roughly equal performance. Perhaps that is a disappointing result, but it is consistent with the “public choice” theories favored by many free-market economists.
A third kind of privatization is when business adds a layer of activity to a preexisting government function. For instance, some states have “privatized” their Medicaid services by outsourcing Medicaid provision to private health insurers. The Medicaid program has not gone away or been turned over to the private sector — rather, companies have a role in administering the system.
This kind of “layered” privatization, like the second kind of privatization, can work out either for the better or for the worse. One recent study shows this privatization increased the costs of Medicaid significantly without providing offsetting benefits. The private companies have done a good job — for themselves — of extracting more revenue from the system. Yet Medicare Cost Advantage, which creates a private layer of service on top of Medicare, run by insurance companies, does offer significant benefits to those who opt for it.
The lesson here is that talk of “privatization” per se is meaningless without elucidating which kind of privatization is under consideration.
Worth a ponder. Overall I think postal service privatization cannot be too closely tied to crony capitalism if it is going to work.