Month: July 2010

*Jimmy Stewart is dead*

So says Larry Kotlikoff, in his new book, entitled Jimmy Stewart is Dead: Ending the World's Ongoing Financial Plague with Limited Purpose Banking.  It's lively and polemic, and suddenly it lurches into a proposal to reform financial intermediation:

Under limited purposes banking the banks are themselves simply financial intermediaries, while their mutual funds represents mini-banks, if you like, all of which are subject to 100 percent capital requirements.

Explained another way, you hold liquid securities directly and cut out the middleman of the lending bank.  It's like expanding the idea of a checkable money market mutual fund to cover the retail banking sector.  Here is his short Op-Ed on the idea, here is a Business Week article, and here are numerous endorsements for the book.  See also Bob Litan on "narrow banking." 

I used to advocate a version of this idea myself, but I no longer think it is a good reform proposal, for a few reasons: 

1. There aren't enough safe, liquid assets to cover the stock of bank deposits.  There would be even fewer safe, liquid assets if fiscal conservatives had their way.  And we've now learned that the commercial paper market can seize up and shut down and AAA securities aren't always so safe.

2. Holding T-Bills eliminates the need for the bank intermediary and the resulting problems of moral hazard.  But remember — these ends are achieved only by lending that money to the government.  What's the old saying?: out of the frying pan, into the fire…

3. A lot of what current banks do would be replicated by non-bank commercial lenders and the risk of the banking sector would be transferred somewhere else.  Ideally, these non-bank lenders would engage in greater "maturity-matching," but if banks will exploit the moral hazard problem won't these lenders exploit it too?  The financial crisis very much changed my mind on this question.  Can't such lenders, to policymakers, appear "too big to fail" in the same way that standard banks do?  Are General Motors, AIG, and GE Credit really the path to future financial sector safety?  Maybe there is room for improvement, by using more commercial lending, but it is murky and I no longer see a clear gain in this regard.

Here, by the way, is a Bert Ely critique.

The world’s largest database of job openings for economists

It is here and the bottom line is this:

Starting from today, walras.org and VoxEU.org have joined forces to form the largest global database of job openings for PhD economists. Any job posted on walras.org is automatically also posted on VoxEU’s new job market database, which can be accessed by clicking here.

You can also access the Jobs section directly using the new Jobs tab in the main navigation or by linking to www.voxeu.org/jobs/

The speed of labor market adjustment

Ezra Klein reports:

Notice that adding new jobs at a rate of 200,000 a month would take us 150 months — or 12.5 years — to get back to normalcy. So far, only April has seen more than 200,000 in non-census jobs growth — and even then, just barely.

This in my view is a puzzle for all theories of labor market adjustment.  Why does it take so long?  This isn't one of those West European scenarios where, due to benefits, being unemployed is permanently somewhat attractive alternative for some subset of the work force.  Nor is the United States a country where employers cannot fire recalcitrant workers.

If monetary velocity fell by eleven percent, is it the view of the Keynesians that the required nominal wage adjustment takes so many years?  Hysteresis means that unemployment gets "baked in" to some extent, but if anything you might expect that to speed up shorter-term adjustment in the work force, to avoid such a fate.

Does the required "recalculation" take so long?  I find myself coming back to the view that many previously employed workers simply have a current marginal product pretty close to zero.

Addendum: Arnold Kling comments.

Excludability depends on technology

Eric Crampton alerts me to the following idea:

Design student Fabian Brunsing has devised a fiendish device that makes pay toilets seem positively munificent: Dubbed “Pay & Sit: The Private Bench,” it consists of a bench covered with retractable metal spikes and a coin slot. If you want to sit down on the bench without an array of spikes jamming you in the keister, you’ve got to pay €0.50 (about 70 cents US).

As seen below, this causes the spikes to retract so you can sit on the bench, and also activates a timer. Shortly before the timer expires, you’re warned by a buzzer to get up; then, the spikes shoot back up. Beware!

Of course actual privatized benches, as you might find them in a shopping mall, do not usually embed this device.

Is Creativity Declining?

Nobody would argue that Torrance’s tasks, which have become the gold standard in creativity assessment, measure creativity perfectly. What’s shocking is how incredibly well Torrance’s creativity index predicted those kids’ creative accomplishments as adults. Those who came up with more good ideas on Torrance’s tasks grew up to be entrepreneurs, inventors, college presidents, authors, doctors, diplomats, and software developers. The correlation to lifetime creative accomplishment was more than three times stronger for childhood creativity than childhood IQ.

Like intelligence tests, Torrance’s test–a 90-minute series of discrete tasks, administered by a psychologist–has been taken by millions worldwide in 50 languages. Yet there is one crucial difference between IQ and CQ scores. With intelligence, there is a phenomenon called the Flynn effect–each generation, scores go up about 10 points. Enriched environments are making kids smarter. With creativity, a reverse trend has just been identified and is being reported for the first time here: American creativity scores are falling.

From Newsweek.  I am not at all convinced that creativity is on the decline.  The study cited seems to be unpublished and there isn't much on the author's website which is a little, well, too creative for my tastes.  Nevertheless, the Torrance test and its correlation with lifetime creative is interesting and a good reminder of what IQ tests do not reveal.  I also liked this bit:

When faculty of a major Chinese university asked Plucker to identify trends in American education, he described our focus on standardized curriculum, rote memorization, and nationalized testing. “After my answer was translated, they just started laughing out loud,” Plucker says. “They said, ‘You’re racing toward our old model. But we’re racing toward your model, as fast as we can.’ “

How should we define money? (warning: this post is pure semantics)

E. Barandiaran writes in the comments:

Tyler, I hope that tomorrow (7/14) you read this comment about Arnold Kling's challenge to BC: define money that meets two requirements. Please tell AK that his two requirements were the same that Milton F. argued for the QT of M to make sense –but as anyone familiar with the history of Milton's version knows, he failed miserably. I'm still waiting your definition of money.

Arnold Kling writes:

So my challenge for Bryan (and for the rest of the profession, because I am the one who is out on a limb on this) is to come up with a definition of money that satisfies two criteria. First, your monetary aggregate is correlated with nominal GDP in a reliable way (with "reliable" including that if you were to target it, the relationship would not fall apart). Second, the Fed controls that monetary aggregate reasonably closely.

No definition of money fits Arnold's challenge (though Bryan argues for the monetary base) and I'm not going to offer a single definition of money, period.  I see money first as a medium of account and then as an option on purchasing goods and services.  As an option, "money" is more like "credit cards" than many economists might find comfortable, but so be it.  No single number very well summarizes the quantity or outstanding value of the money supply, properly understood to include the option value of lines of credit but also the option value of currency and bank reserves.  (Bill Barnett promotes "divisia indices," which I view as a nice try to a hard-to-solve problem.)

That said, a large, exogenous shift in the money supply will raise the general level of prices.  There is overwhelming evidence for that proposition (check out my macro Principles text with Alex, for one good chart, or visit Zimbabwe).  If some mix of currency, bank reserves, and useful lines of credit go up, prices will go up too, in very rough proportion, no matter what the exact measure of the money supply should be.

A lot of the better criticisms of the quantity theory play off of whether "money" is exogenous in the first place.  Many of the points of these critics are well-taken, but still a properly specified exogenous boost in the money supply will bring the traditional quantity theory result.  You just don't have to see that exogenous shift as the only relevant scenario for all real world monetary economics.

I see this post as "a lot of words."  I'm not saying much, I am just trying to limit how much other people's words confuse you.

On the quantity theory, I recommend reading and studying Arthur Marget's A Theory of Prices, especially volume II.  Marget was a penetrating thinker who understood his chosen topics better than anyone else and who was very good at pulling out the deep truths in apparently simple propositions.  I think of him as the Scott Sumner of his day, minus a blog.

How to watch and rewatch movies

Andrew Fischer Lees, a loyal MR reader, asks:

Tyler and Alex, do either of you find yourself re-watching movies? 

If you see it in the theatres, will you re-watch it on your own home TV? My personal rules is to watch each movie only once in theatres, so as to have the most entertaining recollection of the movie as possible.  That said, movies that are quite plot or character driven, and that contain minimal audio/visual candy (e.g. Goodnight and Good Luck), often are exceptions to this rule.  Any strategy that you (or your readers) employ?

I have a few (loose) principles here:

1. I will rewatch action movies, but preferably on a big screen.  I don't like to downgrade my experience of a movie, if I can help it.  Avoiding the downgrade is the #1 principle for movie rewatching.

2. It is rare that I enjoy rewatching comedies, no matter how good they were the first time around.

3. I am most likely to benefit from rewatching slow and complex dramas, especially those not in English.  I am interested in learning something from the rewatch, not just replicating a familiar experience of cackling pleasure or glee.  Tarkovsky movies are my nomination for those which bear the highest returns from rewatching, Godard movies too.  Rewatching good Hitchcock movies does not bore me.

Here are informal data on the most rewatched movies.  What principles can you all suggest?

Gender Parity in Schooling Around the World

The world has reached gender parity in schooling and in a few years we will see a schooling ratio in favor of women.  Using UNESCO statistics (more detail here) on school life expectancy, the average country has a parity level of 1.01 in favor of women or, weighting by population, .991.  In other words, at current rates women can be expected to get the same number of years of education as men, as a world average.

Equal life expectancy of schooling on a world level does not mean that all is well – basically we have a relatively small number of countries in which women get much less education than men and a large number of countries in which women get somewhat more education than men.  On the vertical axis in the figure below (click to enlarge) is total life expectancy in school and on the horizontal axis the ratio of female to male life expectancy in school.  The figure tells us a number of interesting things.  First, the largest imbalances are against women and these tend to occur in countries with a low level of total education.  South Korea is an interesting outlier.

Second, in India parity is below 1 and in China it is above 1.  In India female school life expectancy increased by a huge 2.5 years between 2000 and 2007 and the parity ratio increased from .77 to .9 so we can expect the (weighted) world parity level to easily tip over 1 in the next few years (if it has not done so already). The graph suggests that a ratio around 1.09 is the "norm" towards which countries are trending with development.

Interestingly, some of the Muslim countries, such as Pakistan and Afghanistan (no data for 2007-2008 but in 2004 the parity ratio was less than 0.5), are below parity but Qatar and Iran have some of the highest ratios in the world, both above US levels.

Parity

Are we relying too much on behavioral economics?

George Loewenstein and Peter Ubel say yes.  Often there is no nudge-based free lunch and we need a straightforward relative price shift:

Behavioral economics should complement, not substitute for, more substantive economic interventions. If traditional economics suggests that we should have a larger price difference between sugar-free and sugared drinks, behavioral economics could suggest whether consumers would respond better to a subsidy on unsweetened drinks or a tax on sugary drinks.

But that’s the most it can do. For all of its insights, behavioral economics alone is not a viable alternative to the kinds of far-reaching policies we need to tackle our nation’s challenges.

There is much more here, hat tip to Mark Thoma.  Loewenstein, of course, is one of the pioneers of…behavioral economics.  (If you're wondering, I don't agree with a number of their examples, but I do agree with their overall point.)

*Vietnam: Rising Dragon*

It might seem strange, given the system's surveillance and security networks, but the Communist Party is wary of high-profile law enforcement campaigns.  Failure would be worse than embarrassing for a party which is supposed to represent the people's will.  Such campaigns are only ever risked at times and in ways which demonstrate the Party's continuing hold on power.

That is from Bill Hayton's new book — Vietnam: Rising Dragon — which I found informative and insightful on virtually every page.  Recommended.

What your blogging style shows

Here are a few sentences to ponder:

Some commentators have suggested that the internet allows people to present idealised versions of themselves to the world. Contrary to that idea, Yarkoni found that bloggers' choice of words consistently related to their personality type just as has been found in past offline research.

More neurotic bloggers used more words associated with negative emotions; extravert bloggers used more words pertaining to positive emotions; high scorers on agreeableness avoided swear words and used more words related to communality; and conscientious bloggers mentioned more words with achievement connotations.

Can we all agree that the cited post represents a considerable success?  And might it apply to blog commentators as well?

Addendum: Arnold Kling comments.