Tuesday assorted links
1. Stephen Miran makes the case for twenty percent tariffs (WSJ). You can run this one through o1 pro yourself.
2. The history of export controls on IP.
3. Jacob Trefethen, on reforming science funding.
4. In ex-Soviet States, the mental health of the young seems fine.
5. New Ashlee Vance sci-tech media venture. Site here.
The Borda Count is the Best Method of Voting
It’s well known that the voting methods we use are highly defective, as they fail to meet fundamental criteria like positive responsiveness, the Pareto principle, and stability. Positive responsiveness (monotonicity) means that if a candidate improves on some voters’ ballots, this should not reduce the candidate’s chances of winning. Yet, many voting methods, including runoffs and ranked-choice voting, fail positive responsiveness. In other words, candidates who became more preferred by voters can end up losing when they would have won when they were less preferred! It’s even more shocking that some voting systems can fail the Pareto principle, which simply says that if every voter prefers x to y then the voting system should not rank y above x. Everyone knows that in a democracy a candidate may be elected that the minority ranks below another possible candidate but how many know that there are democratic voting procedures where a candidate may be elected that the majority ranks below another possible candidate or even that democratic voting procedures may elect a candidate that everyone ranks below another possible candidate! That is the failure of the Pareto principle and the chaos results of McKelvey–Schofield show that this kind of outcome should be expected.
Almost all researchers in social choice understand the defects of common voting systems and indeed tend to agree that the most common system, first past the post voting, is probably the most defective! But, as no system is perfect, there has been less consensus on which methods are best. Ranked choice voting, approval voting and the Borda Count all have their proponents. In recent years, however, there has been a swing towards the Borda Count.
Don Saari, for example, whose work on voting has been a revelation, has made strong arguments in favor of the Borda Count. The Borda Count has voter rank the n candidates from most to least preferred and assigns (n-1) points to the candidates. For example if there are 3 candidates a voter’s top-ranked candidate gets 2 points, the second ranked candidate gets 1 point and the last ranked candidate 0 points. The candidate with the most points overall wins.
The Borda Count satisfies positive responsiveness, the Pareto principle and stability. In addition, Saari points out that the Borda Count is the only positional voting system to always rank a Condorcet winner (a candidate who beats every other candidate in pairwise voting) above a Condorcet loser (a candidate who loses to every other candidate in pairwise voting.) In addition, all voting systems are gameable, but Saari shows that the Borda Count is by some reasonable measures the least or among the least gameable systems.
My own work in voting theory shows, with a somewhat tongue in cheek but practical example, that the Borda Count would have avoided the civil war! I also show that other systems such as cumulative voting or approval voting are highly open to chaos, as illustrated by the fact that under approval voting almost anything could have happened in the Presidential election of 1992, including Ross Perot as President.
One reason the Borda Count performs well is that it uses more information than other systems. If you just use a voter’s first place votes, you are throwing out a lot of information about how a voter ranks second and third candidates. If you just use pairwise votes you are throwing out a lot of information about the entire distribution of voter rankings. When you throw out information the voting system can’t distinguish rational from irrational voters which is one reason why the outcomes of a voting system can look irrational.
Eric Maskin has an important new contribution to this literature. Arrow’s Independence of Irrelevant Alternatives (IIA) says that if no voters change their rankings of x and y then the social ranking of x and y shouldn’t change. In other words, if no voter changes their ranking of Bush and Gore then the outcome of the election shouldn’t change regardless of how Nader is ranked (for the pedantic I exclude the case where Nader wins.) The motivation for IIA seems reasonable, we don’t want spoilers who split a candidate’s vote allowing a less preferred candidate, even a Condorcet loser to win. But IIA also excludes information about preference intensity from the voting system and throwing out information is rarely a good idea.
What Maskin shows is that it’s possible to keep the desirable properties of IIA while still measuring preference intensity with what he calls modified IIA, although in my view a better name would be middle IIA. Modified or middle IIA says that an alternative z should be irrelevant unless it is in the middle of x and y, e.g. x>z>y. More precisely, we allow the voting system to change the ranking of x and y if the ranking of z moves in or out of the middle of x and y but not otherwise (recall IIA would forbid the social ranking of x and y to change if no voter changes their ranking of x and y).
Maskin shows that the Borda Count is the only voting system which satisfies MIIA and a handful of other desirable and unobjectionable properties. It follows that the Borda Count is the only voting system to both measure preference intensity and to avoid defects such as a spoilers.
The debates over which is the best voting system will probably never end. Indeed, voting theory itself tells us that multi-dimensional choice is always subject to some infirmities and people may differ on which infirmities they are willing to accept. Nevertheless, we can conclude that plurality rule is a very undesirable voting system and the case for the Borda Count is strong.
What should I ask Greg Clark?
Yes, I will be having a Conversation with him. Gregory Clark the economist. Here is his Wikipedia page. So what should I ask?
The circulation of elites, sort of
Is the top tail of wealth a set of fixed individuals or is there substantial turnover? We estimate upper-tail wealth dynamics during the Gilded Age and beyond, a time of rapid wealth accumulation and concentration in the late 19th and early 20th centuries. Using various wealth proxies and data tracking tens of millions of individuals, we find that most extremely wealthy individuals drop out of the top tail within their lifetimes. Yet, elite wealth still matters. We find a non-linear association between grandparental wealth and being in the top 1%, such that having a rich grandparent exponentially increases the likelihood of reaching the top 1%. Still, over 90% of the grandchildren of top 1% wealth grandfathers did not achieve that level.
That is from a new NBER working paper by Priti Kalsi and Zachary Ward.
Principles, from Nabeel
14. You don’t do anyone any favors by lurking, put yourself out there!
15. If you don’t “get” a classic book or movie, 90% of the time it’s your fault. (It might just not be the right time for you to appreciate that thing.)
16. If you find yourself dreading Mondays, quit…
23. Doing things is energizing, wasting time is depressing. You don’t need that much ‘rest’.
24. Being able to travel is one of the key ways the modern world is better than the old world. Learn to travel well.
Here is the full list.
Monday assorted links
1. Cairo norms and multiple equilibria?
2. Straussian, clever language though not as sharp as the Everly Brothers. I wish them the best.
3. The declining influence of economists in policy circles (NYT).
5. Weird things going on in Romania, poorly understood.
Canada’s Comparative Advantages
Jay Martin writes a provocative post, Has Canada Become a Jamaican Bobsled Team?
if Canada were to become a state, it would be the third poorest in the country, right behind Alabama.
Everybody talks about the American debt issue, but Canadian households bear more debt relative to their income than any other G7 country. The average Canadian now spends 15% of their income on debt servicing.
This is a stark shift from 2008 when Canada emerged from the global financial crisis with a healthier balance sheet than any other G7 nation.
One indicator I pay close attention to is corporate investment per worker.
Every year, businesses invest in growth – new technology, new projects, new employees or products. If you take the total number that businesses invest during a calendar year, and divide that by the number of active workers in the country, you get the corporate investment per worker.
In the U.S., businesses invest about $28,000 per worker. In Canada, that number is only $15,000—nearly half.
Corporate investment is what drives future productivity, economic growth, and opportunity. The higher the number, the brighter the future.
What is Canada’s comparative advantage?
…we have vast natural resources, we have easy-to-navigate geography, we have the world’s longest coastline that spans three oceans – allowing direct access to every global market, and the largest shared international land border, on the other side of which is the worlds wealthiest, hungriest customer.
We have product. And we have a direct line to the consumer.
We are not capitalizing on these advantages because we have been sold a narrative discouraging investment in the industries where we outperform the world.
…The narrative that Canada should abandon its resource sector to pursue conceptual industries like hydrogen power or electric vehicle production is both misguided and damaging. These are fields where Canada has little experience or infrastructure, we are not competitive, and the evidence is in our economic data.
I would add one point. The issue shouldn’t be framed as extracting natural resources versus high-tech investment, as if mining, oil and gas, lumber and agriculture were simple brute-labor industries. In fact, there is plenty of room for artificial intelligence to dramatically increase the rate at which profitable mines are discovered. Industrial robotics and automation are the future of mining. Agriculture is a high-tech industry from genetic engineering to robotic laser weeding to satellite based based crop monitoring.
Indeed, Canada’s best chance to stay at the forefront of technology lies in exploiting its comparative advantages.
The Acemoglu arguments against high-skilled immigration
Here is Daron Acemoglu’s Project Syndicate piece, mostly critical on high-skilled immigration.
Here is the first argument from Acemoglu:
…one would expect corporate America’s growing need for skilled STEM workers to translate into advocacy for, and investments in, STEM education. But an overreliance on the H-1B program may have broken this link and made American elites indifferent to the widely recognized failures of the US education system. Put differently, the problem may not be a cultural veneration of mediocrity, as Ramaswamy argued, but rather neglect on the part of business leaders, intellectual elites, and politicians.
o1 responds. Here is Acemoglu’s second argument:
Even as H-1B workers boost innovation, their presence may affect the direction innovation takes. My own work shows (theoretically and empirically) that when the supply of skilled labor increases, technology choices start favoring such workers. Over the last several decades, businesses have increasingly adopted technologies that favor high-skill workers and automate tasks previously performed by lower-skill workers. While this trend may have been driven by other factors, too, the availability of affordable high-skill workers for the tech industry plausibly contributed to it.
The third argument about brain drain has enough qualifications and admissions that it isn’t really a criticism. In any case my colleague Michael Clemens, among others, has shown that the brain drain argument applies mainly to very small countries. But if you wish, run it through AI yourself.
If all I knew were this “exchange,” I would conclude that o1 and o1 pro were better economists — much better — than one of our most recent Nobel Laureates, and also the top cited economist of his generation. Noah Smith also is critical.
Via Mike Doherty.
The Greenland debates
I would say we have not yet figured out what is the best U.S. policy toward Greenland, nor have we figured out best stances for either Greenland or Denmark. I am struck however by the low quality of the debate, and I mean on the anti-U.S. side most of all. This is just one clip, but I am hearing very much the same in a number of other interchanges, most of all from Europeans. There is a lot of EU pearl-clutching, and throwing around of adjectives like “colonialist” or “imperialist.” Or trying to buy Greenland is somehow analogized to Putin not trying to buy Ukraine. Or the word “offensive” is deployed as if that were an argument, or the person tries to switch the discussion into an attack on Trump and his rhetoric.
C’mon, people!
De facto, you are all creating the impression that Greenland really would be better off under some other arrangement. Why not put forward a constructive plan for improving Greenland? It would be better yet to cite a current plan under consideration (is there one?). “We at the EU, by following this plan, will give Greenland a better economic and security future than can the United States.” If the plan is decent, Greenland will wish to break off the talks with America it desires. (To be clear, I do not think they desire incorporation. This FT piece strikes me as the best so far on the debates.)
Or if you must stick to the negative, put forward some concrete arguments for how greater U.S. involvement in Greenland would be bad for global security, bad for economic growth, bad for the U.S., or…something. “Your EU allies won’t like it,” or “Trump’s behavior is unacceptable” isn’t enough and furthermore the first of those is question-begging.
It is time to rise to the occasion.
p.s. I still am glad we bought the Danish West Indies in 1917. Nor do I hear many Danes, or island natives, complain about this.
My podcast with Andrew Xu
I had fun, and Andrew writes:
In this episode, I got a chance to talk with Tyler about quite a few of those topics: the extent of his libertarian ideology, why he’s less pessimistic about social media, what movies have influenced him, etc.
Here is the Spotify link.
Sunday assorted links
1. Cracks in the silence about Havana Syndrome (Atlantic).
2. “As Rainer Zitelmann, a noted historian of the Third Reich, has pointed out, the AfD has long since abandoned its former economic liberalism for a Right-wing form of anti-capitalism. Its rhetoric is often indistinguishable from that of the far-Left Die Linke, or the Left populist Bündnis Sahra Wagenknecht.” (Brendan Simms in the Telegraph)
3. “Australia appoints first rabbit tsar to combat invasive species.” (FT)
4. o1 pro answers a question about intra-profile social welfare theory, a’la Kevin Roberts. Wake up, people! I start it off with the Harberger tax model, but perhaps that is too easy to still be impressive these days?
5. University of Chicago economics professor Casey Mulligan appointed Chief Counsel for Advocacy at the U.S. Small Business Administration.
6. The law and economics of a fire disaster. And Schoenberg archive destroyed by the fire.
Facts about U.S. employment
First, the labor market is no longer polarizing— employment in low- and middle-paid occupations has declined, while highly paid employment has grown. Second, employment growth has stalled in low-paid service jobs. Third, the share of employment in STEM jobs has increased by more than 50 percent since 2010, fueled by growth in software and computer-related occupations. Fourth, retail sales employment has declined by 25 percent in the last decade, likely because of technological improvements in online retail.
That is from a recent NBER working paper by David J. Deming, Christopher Ong, and Lawrence M. Summers.
Canada’s missing entrepreneurs
Companies in Argentina (from my email)
From Krzysztof Tyszka-Drozdowski:
Every weekend, I try to go through interesting articles about Argentina. Here’s something from La Nación that surprised me: it discusses the relatively weak standing of Argentine companies internationally. (https://www.lanacion.com.ar/opinion/las-empresas-argentinas-ante-un-cambio-de-perfil-nid11012025/):
– only 3 of the top 50 largest Latin American companies are Argentine (22 are Brazilian, 14 Mexican, and 8 Chilean). Moreover, only 7 of the top 100 largest Latin American companies are Argentine.
– there are just about $50 billion invested by Argentine companies abroad; compared to $300 billion from Brazil, $215 billion from Mexico, $140 billion from Chile, and $75 billion from Colombia.
Argentina still has a long way to go!
>By the way, what would be your answer to the question: why is Argentina not Australia? I’m currently reading the book ‘Por qué Argentina no fue Australia’ by Gerchunoff and Fajgelbaum, which discusses this topic.
*The Brutalist* (no real spoilers)
As I kept watching, I was thinking “well, this is pretty good but it isn’t great.” But by the time the final scene rolled around, I was convinced. A few points:
1. The Hungarian wife is the best character.
2. The title “The Brutalist” does not refer solely to the architect.
3. The industrial landscapes and shots of an earlier America are excellent.
4. The movie never felt too long, and that is at 3.5 hours.
5. It is an explicitly pro-Israel movie, and that angle I was not expecting at all.
6. The movie does make an actual case for brutalism in architecture. Note the architect and main character starts off as a modernist, not a brutalist.
7. Do pay attention to how this movie “rewrites” Casablanca.
Recommended, for some.